SHIFTING PATTERNS FROM DEFINED BENEFIT TO DEFINED CONTRIBUTIONS AN EMPIRICAL ANALYSIS OF SELECTED OECD COUNTRIES

http://dx.doi.org/10.31703/ger.2022(VII-I).15      10.31703/ger.2022(VII-I).15      Published : Mar 2022
Authored by : Arslan Qayyum , Aniqa Arslan , Shariq Ayyubi

15 Pages : 177-193

    Abstract:

    The goal of the study is to find out how the growth of pension funds and their accumulation factors are related. Step-wise regression approach was utilized on a dynamic panel data model to verify the individual significance of included variables in the model systematically in order to bring out the core accumulation elements which are driving the pension fund's development, and R2-change was observed for this purpose. The study explores that OECD economies behave differently on the bases of their growth perspective i.e., Defined Benefits, and Employers' Contributions are positively contributing to pension funds in HGO economies and negative in LGO ones, showing that DB is hardly practised in the latter ones and is replaced by DC plan. The approach utilized in this article could be of practical value to policymakers and data analysts in OECD pension funds departments when making decisions on pension fund governance and the underlying fundamental drivers.

    Key Words:

    Pension Funds’ Growth, Defined Contribution, Defined Benefit, Occupation Pension Funds, Employee Contribution, Employer Contribution

    Introduction

    Pension funds play a key part in the healthy functioning of people's social lives, especially senior individuals who seek a factor of confidence against unsafe situations, i.e. when they are unemployed. Pension fund performance and governance have been studied. The current study attempts to highlight the important growth and use characteristics of pension funds. OECD pension funds forecast only presents the descriptive study for pension fund utilization,

    not their particular major implications.

    These institutions assist workers to save for retirement during their working lives. In most countries, pension funds cannot be withdrawn early, which creates long-term holdings by pension corporations and opens doors for investment opportunities to provide higher returns. When analysing OECD economies, pension funds must be considered. OECD pension funds' average asset weight is 89%. (OECD, 2020). Considering governance and growth determinants of pension funds is a must. Moreover, the ageing factor in OECD economies makes pension fund management 

    increasingly crucial.

    A number of past studies were surveyed to form the current study and support its formation. Table 1. Describes them briefly.

    Table 1

    . Accumulation-Factors of Pension Funds in Selected-OECD Countries

    Abbr.

    Construct

    Association

    Past Studies

    Theoretical Relation

    PFG

    Pension Funds Growth

    DV

    Roce, Kaminker, & Stewart (2011); Casey, (2014); Alonso, et al. (2010)

    Immunization Theory

    OPF

    Occupational Pension Funds

    P

    Lamla, & Coppola, (2013); Haukenes, (2011); Ahola, (2009); Palme, & Svensson, (1997); Faccio, & Lasfer, (2000)

    Theory of Pooling+ Welfarists Approach

    PPF

    Private Pension Funds

    P

    Poterba, Venti, & Wise, (2001); Perozek, & Reinsdorf, (2002); Konstantin, (2007); Augusto, & Dimitri, (1992); Mayhew, & Smith, (2014);

    Theory of Pooling + Prodigal Father Probability Theory

    PIC

    Pension Insurance Contracts

    P

    Guo et al. (2016); Ha, (2017); Cheng, (2015); Chen, Hentschel, & Klein, (2015); Van Praag, B. M. S., & Hop, (2018);

    Theory of Pooling

    DBF

    Defined Benefit Funds

    PN

    Copeland, & VanDerhei (2009); Poterba et al. (2007); Pesando, (2008); Stiff, Sharpe, & Atkinson, (2005); Lucas, & Zeldes, (2007);

    Theory of Pooling + Life Cycle Theory+ Human Capital Spill-over Theory

    DBT

    Defined Benefit Traditional

    PN

    Clark, Glickstein, & Hill, (2013); Zhu, Hardy, & Saunders, (2017); Heeder, (2010); Dydo, (2005); Zhu, Hardy, & Saunders, (2018); Poterba et al. (2007)

    Theory of Pooling

    DBM

    Defined Benefit Mixed or Hybrid

    PN

    Theory of Pooling

    DC

    Defined Contribution Fund

    P

    Benartzi, & Thaler, (2001); Holzmann, & Palmer, (2006); Choi et al. (2002); Cairns, Blake, & Dowd, (2006); Huberman, Iyengar, & Jiang, (2007);

    Theory of Pooling+ Prodigal Father Probability Theory

    DCP

    Defined Contribution Protected Fund

    P

    Boulier, Huang, & Taillard, (2001); Fronstin, (2001); Auerbach, & Lee, (2006); Gerrard, Huberman, & Vigna, (2004); Holzmann, Palmer, & Robalino, (2012);

    Theory of Pooling

    DCU

    Defined Contribution Unprotected Fund

    P

    Theory of Pooling

    ESTC

    Employees' Contributions

    P

    Byrne, (2007); Toshiki, (2009); Zhang, (2011); Njogu, (2014);

    Theory of Pooling

    ERTC

    Employers' Contributions

    PN

    Olsen, & VanDerhei, (1997); Engelhardt, (2011); Chen, & Wu, (2014); Ghilarducci, & Sun, (2006); Pensions, (2004);

    Theory of Pooling+ Welfarists Approach

    OE

    Operating Expenses

    N

    Bateman, & Mitchell, (2004); Jiang, (2011); Collins, (2003); Obinata, (2000); Militaru, (2015);

    Accounting Profitability Theory+ Absolute Matching Concept

    Table 2

    . Depicts the relationship of each of the above hypotheses with pension fund growth.

    Accumulation-Factors of Pension Funds in Selected-OECD Countries

    Abbreviation

    Construct

    Criteria

    Formula

    PFG

    Pension Funds Growth

    Per cent

    (Recent funds - Last years' funds)/Last year funds*100)

    Korkmaz, (2015)

    OPA

    Occupational Pension Funds

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of Occupational Pension Funds as measured by OECD Library

    Palme, & Svensson, (1997); Faccio, & Lasfer, (2000)

    PPF

    Private Pension Funds

    The US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of private pension funds as measured by OECD Library

    Augusto, & Dimitri, (1992); Mayhew, & Smith, (2014);

    PIC

    Pension Insurance Contracts

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of pension insurance contracts as measured by OECD Library. Chen, Hentschel, & Klein, (2015); Van Praag, B. M. S., & Hop, (2018);

    DB

    Defined Benefit Funds

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of defined benefit funds as measured by OECD Library

    Stiff, Sharpe, & Atkinson, (2005); Lucas, & Zeldes, (2007);

    DBT

    Defined Benefit Traditional

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of defined benefit traditional funds as measured by OECD Library. Zhu, Hardy, & Saunders, (2018); Poterba et al. (2007)

    DBM

    Defined Benefit Mixed or Hybrid

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of defined benefit mixed or hybrid funds as measured by OECD Library. Zhu, Hardy, & Saunders, (2018); Poterba et al. (2007)

    DC

    Defined Contribution Fund

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of defined contribution funds as measured by OECD Library. Cairns, Blake, & Dowd, (2006); Huberman, Iyengar, & Jiang, (2007);

    DCP

    Defined Contribution Protected Fund

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of defined contribution protected funds as measured by OECD Library. Gerrard, Haberman, & Vigna, (2004); Holzmann, Palmer, & Robalino, (2012);

    DCU

    Defined Contribution Unprotected Fund

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of defined contribution unprotected funds as measured by OECD Library. Gerrard, Haberman, & Vigna, (2004); Holzmann, Palmer, & Robalino, (2012);

    ESTC

    Employees' Contributions

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of employees' contributions as measured by OECD Library. Ag & C, (2002); Njogu, (2014);

    ERTC

    Emloyers' Contributions

    US. Million Dollars

    Total assets of employers' contributions as measured by OECD Library. Ghilarducci, & Sun, (2006); Pensions, (2005);

    OE

    Operating Expenses

    US. Million Dollars

    Total expenses of pension management as measured by OECD Library. ); Obinata, (2000); Militaru, (2015);

    Theoretical Framework

    Figure 2 describes the factors of accumulation i.e. firstly; three main contributing factors are occupational pension funds (OPA), private pension funds (PPF), and pension insurance contract assets (PIC). Secondly, occupational pension funds are then further divided into defined benefits (DB), defined contributions (DC), employees' contributions (EMPSC), and employers' contributions (EMPRC). Thirdly, DB and DC are further subdivided into defined benefit mixed or hybrid (DBM) plus traditional defined benefit pension assets (TDB) and protected defined contributions (PDC) plus unprotected defined contribution pension funds (UDC) respectively. The purpose of this part of the study is to analyze the significant impact (along with the magnitude and direction) of each of the above-mentioned described factors on the growth of pension funds. Moreover, from the literature review, it is observed that administrative and legal expenses also play a vital role in the growth of pension funds. Hence, this factor is also considered important to be a part of this analysis. 

    Data and Methodology

    Data were obtained from many sources, including the OECD and the profile of each country. The Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) had 36 members by the end of 2018. Only 24 countries that joined the OECD before 1975 were included. It includes statistics from 1975 to 2017 from 24 selected OECD nations, totalling 43 years. This balanced panel data has 1032 total observations. Twelve nations were deleted from the 36-country OECD because of a delay in joining after 1975. 

    The countries selected are separated into two groups on the basis of their median GDP growth. For this reason, an average of each country's pension funds to GDP ratio was calculated. These averages of 24 countries were then used to calculate the median value. As a rule of thumb, countries with a PF/GDP ratio over the median level are regarded higher-growth countries, while those with a PF/GDP ratio below the threshold level are deemed lower-growth nations.  

    Figure 3: Low Growth OECD countries

    Using dynamic panel data and forward step-wise regression, the study compares high-growth-oriented nations with low-growth-oriented countries based on the observed characteristics of selected OECD countries. 

    Economic Model

    General economic functions are provided by the models listed below. With the use of accumulation factors, the growth of a country's pension funds can be modelled mathematically using Equation 1. In addition, these country-based characteristics are expanded upon in (2), which states that they are occupational pension assets (OPA), private pension funds' assets (PPFA), private insurance contract assets (PICA), defined benefit pension funds (DB), defined benefit traditional funds (DBT), defined benefit mixed funds (DBM), defined contributions (DC), defined contributions protected funds (DCP), defined contributions unprotected funds (DCU), employees' contributions (ESTC), employers' contributions (ERTC), and operating and administrative expenses (OE) which are incurred to generate revenue. 

    PFG=f(Accumulation Factors of PF )..(1)

    PFG=(?PFG?_(t-1),OPA,PPFA,PICA,DB,DBT,DBM,DC,DCP,DCU,ESTC,ERTC,OE) --- (2)

    Econometric Model

    On the basis of the model presented above, a dynamic panel data technique was employed, and the three equations that follow i.e.; model-1 show the effect of three main accumulation factors on PFG, i.e., OPA, PPFA and PICA. This model is extended in equation (4) and OPA was subdivided into DB and DC funds and the other two variables PPFA and PICA remain the same in the model. Moreover, equation (5) further segregates the model and subdivides the DB funds into DBT & DBM and DC funds into DCP & DCU respectively. 

    PFG (OECD) it = ?0 + ?i D it + ?1 (PFG) i, t-1 + ?2 (OPA) it + ?3 (PPFA) it + ?4 (PICA) it + ? it ____ (3)

    PFG (OECD) it = ?0 + ?i D it + ?1 (PFG) i, t-1 + ?2 (DBA) it + ?3 (DCA) it + ?4 (PPFA) it + ?5 (PICA) it + ? it ____ (4)

    PFG (OECD) it = ?0 + ?i D it + ?1 (PFG) i, t-1 + ?2 (DBT) it + ?3 (DBM) it + ?4 (DCP) it + ?5 (DCU) it + ?6 (ESTC) it + ?7 (ESRC) it + ?8 (OE) it + ? it ____ (5)

    Where:

    PFG = Pension Funds Growth

    OPA = Occupational Pension Funds’ Assets

    PPFA = Personal Pension Funds’ Assets

    PICA = Pension Insurance Contracts’ Assets

    DB = Defined Benefit Funds

    DBT = Defined Benefits Traditional

    DBM = Defined Benefit Mixed/Hybrid

    DC = Defined Contribution Funds

    DCP = Protected Defined Contributions

    DCU = Unprotected Defined Contributions

    ESTC =  Employees’ Contributions

    ERTC = Employers’ Contributions

    OE = Operating and Administrative Expenses

    ? = the error term

    Results Analysis and Discussion

    Table 3 shows the summary and there is also a correlation matrix and VIF analysis of the data in tables 4, 5, and 6. Using DPD-Hierarchical regression analysis, Table 7 presents a comparison of the Whole-sample, HGO-Countries, and LGO-Countries. Three models were created for each analysis based on the already mentioned three equations i.e., 3, 4 and 5: model 1, model 2, and model 3. For this study, the growth of pension funds is used as the observed dependent variable, while the lagged values of PFG, OPA, PPFA, PICA, DB, DC, DBT, DBM, DCP, DCU, ESTC, ERTC, and OE are used as independent variables based on the literature. 

    Table 4

    Factors for Accumulation of Pension Funds and Their Relationships

    Variables

    VIF

    PFG

    OPA

    PPFA

    PICA

    DB

    DBT

    DBM

    DC

    DCP

    DCU

    ESTC

    ERTC

    OE

    PFG

     

    1

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

    OPA

    9.89

    0.730*

    1

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

    PPFA

    8.76

    0.344*

    0.396*

    1

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

    PICA

    8.12

    0.332*

    0.365*

    0.284*

    1

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

    DB

    7.97

    0.252*

    0.385*

    0.667*

    0.270*

    1

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

    DBT

    6.41

    -0.221*

    0.337*

    0.268*

    0.372*

    0.396*

    1

     

     

     

     

     

     

     

    DBM

    6.11

    0.352*

    0.518*

    -0.045

    -0.076

    0.066

    -0.025

    1

     

     

     

     

     

     

    DC

    5.86

    0.210*

    0.308*

    0.489*

    0.484*

    0.577*

    0.582*

    -0.033

    1

     

     

     

     

     

    DCP

    4.05

    0.062

    0.115*

    -0.082

    0.039

    -0.047

    -0.044

    -0.04

    -0.01

    1

     

     

     

     

    DCU

    3.67

    0.209*

    0.305*

    0.589*

    0.381*

    0.478*

    0.583*

    -0.032

    0.76*

    -0.036

    1

     

     

     

    ESTC

    2.64

    0.225*

    -0.282*

    -0.09

    -0.086

    -0.059

    -0.058

    -0.014

    -0.037

    -0.102

    -0.037

    1

     

     

    ERTC

    1.34

    -0.317*

    0.310*

    0.116

    0.101

    0.056

    0.055

    0.01

    0.034

    0.015

    0.034

    -0.628*

    1

     

    OE

    1.12

    -0.302*

    0.117

    -0.301

    0.201

    -0.343*

    -0.104

    0.124

    -0.105

    -0.201*

    -0.304

    -0.101

    0.301

    1

    Table 5. Forward-Step-Wise DPD Hierarchical Regression Analysis for this Study

    Whole-Sample of Selected OECD Countries

    Higher-Growth-Oriented Countries

    Lower-Growth-Oriented Countries

    Variables

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    PFG (L1)

    0.355***

    0.145**

    0.149***

    0.139**

    0.312*

    0.224*

    0.323***

    0.192**

    0.341**

    (0.03)

    (0.12)

    (0.07)

    (0.02)

    (0.03)

    (0.03)

    (0.01)

    (0.25)

    (0.21)

    OPF

    0.620***

    0.740**

    0.698**

    (0.0314)

    (0.07)

    (0.09)

    PPF

    0.625***

    0.517***

    0.433**

    0.130**

    0.539**

    0.744***

    (0.033)

    (0.0441)

    (0.27)

    (0.24)

    (0.02)

    (0.75)

    PICF

    0.101***

    0.0865**

    0.120**

    0.235**

    0.213**

    0.251***

    (0.0379)

    (0.0357)

    (0.09)

    (0.03)

    (0.16)

    (0.07)

    DBF

    0.240**

    0.140**

    -0.242*

    (0.029)

    (0.01)

    (0.03)

    DCF

    0.271***

    0.224*

    0.308**

    (0.032)

    (0.03)

    (0.06)

    DBT

    0.137**

    0.169*

    -0.269**

    (0.26)

    (0.15)

    (0.06)

    DBM

    0.179**

    0.146*

    -0.121*

    (0.419)

    (0.04)

    (0.01)

    DCP

    0.37***

    0.226*

    0.323**

    (0.018)

    (0.13)

    (0.05)

    DCU

    0.281**

    0.238**

    0.434*

    (0.122)

    (0.42)

    (0.16)

    ESTC

    0.237**

    0.266**

    0.166*

    (0.107)

    (0.11)

    (0.02)

    ERTC

    0.038***

    0.069**

    -0.013**

    (0.449)

    (0.04)

    (0.01)

    OE

    -0.238***

    -0.112**

    -0.306*

    (0.254)

    (0.03)

    (0.01)

    Constant

    9.255***

    16.99***

    12.148***

    5.721**

    8.744**

    6.272***

    4.232***

    6.690**

    6.842***

    (0.29)

    (0.924)

    (0.737)

    (0.76)

    (0.13)

    (0.45)

    (0.35)

    (0.25)

    (0.76)

    Table 6. Diagnostic Tests for the Study

    Whole-Sample of Selected OECD Countries

    Higher-Growth-Oriented Countries

    Lower-Growth-Oriented Countries

    Variables

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    (1)

    (2)

    (3)

    R-squared

    0.887

    0.934

    0.963

    0.894

    0.942

    0.967

    0.903

    0.945

    0.971

    F-Test

    56.03***

    67.94***

    80.74***

    58.12***

    70.21***

    83.72***

    54.30***

    69.29***

    81.23***

    Hetero (P-value)

    0.0622

    0.0715

    0.0822

    0.0625

    0.0667

    0.0528

    0.0742

    0.0730

    0.0683

    Serial Auto (P-value)

    0.0719

    0.0712

    0.0871

    0.0831

    0.0782

    0.0812

    0.0712

    0.0732

    0.0633

    Hausman-Test

    FE

    FE

    FE

    FE

    FE

    FE

    FE

    FE

    FE

    AIC

    1105.59

    961.67

    836.59

    910.16

    897.11

    840.62

    997.99

    981.85

    918.63

    BIC

    1068.63

    929.54

    808.62

    906.41

    867.16

    812.54

    964.65

    949.43

    887.92

    The OPF is showing a momentous relationship through the development of pension funds in selected OECD countries at 1%, 5% and 5% levels of significance in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. It describes that if the OPF of a country is increased by one per cent, the PFG will also be increased by 0.620%, 0.740% and 0.698% in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. This connection is also reinforced in the works by (Lamla, & Coppola, 2013; Haukenes, 2011; Ahola, 2009). It also provides sustenance to the theory of pooling and the Welfarist approach in the sense that occupational pension funds are a major source of pooling funds. Hence, pooling makes it easier for pension firms to invest in a huge amount of different types of assets to generate a steady return over an extended time. In sum, it provides strong support to the first developed hypothesis for this study i.e., H1 which mentions a strong positive association between OPA and PFG. It is obvious that the coefficient of HGO countries (0.740) is higher as compared to LGO countries (0.698). Hence, it can be said that occupational pension funds are contributing more in HGO countries as compared to LGO countries. 

    Private Pension Funds (PPF)

    While talking about the model (1), the PPF depicts a positive relationship with the growth of pension funds in selected OECD countries at 1%, 5% and 5% levels of significance in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. It describes that if the PPF of a country is increased by one per cent, the PFG will also be increased by 0.625%, 0.433% and 0.539% in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. Moreover, model (2) and model (3) are also depicting the same type of relationship between PPF and PFG. This relationship is also supported in the literature by (Poterba, Venti, & Wise, 2001; Perozek, & Reinsdorf, 2002; Konstantin, 2007). It also provides backing to the theory of pooling according to which private pooling of current resources can give them support when they will be older in the future. It provides strong support to the second developed hypothesis for this study i.e., H2 which mentions a strong positive association between PPA and PFG. By comparing HGO and LGO countries, the coefficients of LGO countries (0.539 and 0.744) are larger as compared to HGO countries (0.433 and 0.130) in model-1 and model-2 respectively. It means the private pension funds are growing faster in LGO countries and more and more people are motivated to have a private pension plan for their future. 

    Pension Insurance Contracts (PIC)

    The PICF highlights a positive relationship with the PFG in selected OECD countries at 1%, 5% and 5% levels of significance in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. It describes that if the PICF of a country is increased by one per cent, the PFG will also be increased by 0.101%, 0.120% and 0.213% in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. Moreover, model (2) and model (3) are also depicting the same type of relationship between PICF and PFG. This relationship is also supported in the literature by (Guo et al. 2016; Ha, 2017; Cheng, 2015). It also provides sustenance to the theory of pooling i.e.; insurance companies provide a platform for pooling funds and investing in different types of investments for the purpose of generating a stable return in the long run. It provides strong support to the third developed hypothesis for this study i.e., H3 which mentions a strong positive association between PICA and PFG. By comparing HGO and LGO countries, the coefficients of LGO countries (0.213 and 0.251) are larger as compared to HGO countries (0.120 and 0.235) in model-1 and model-2 respectively. It means the pension insurance funds are growing faster in LGO countries and more and more people are motivated to have private pension insurance plans for their future.

    Defined Benefit Funds (DBF)

    Defined benefit funds (DBF) is presenting a significant relationship with the growth of pension funds whereas it is showing a significant negative relationship at a 10% level of significance in LGO-Countries. It describes that if the DBF of a country is increased by one per cent, its PFG will also be increased by 0.240% and 0.140% in whole-sample and HGO-Countries respectively. On the other hand, a 1% increase in DBF will decrease the PFG by 0.242% in LGO-Countries. This relationship is also supported in the literature by (Copeland, & VanDerhei 2009; Poterba et al. 2007; Pesando, 2008). It also provides sustenance to the theory of pooling, life cycle theory, and human capital spill-over theory. According to life cycle theory and human capital spill-over theory, current generations should save to feed the elder ones and with the passage of time, when they will be older, their children will feed them in a defined benefit scheme under the PAYG system. In sum, it provides strong support to the fourth developed hypothesis for this study i.e. H4 which mentions a strong positive association between DBF and PFG. By comparing HGO and LGO countries, the coefficient of LGO countries (-0.242) is showing a negative relationship and the coefficient of HGO (0.140) is showing a positive relationship with PFG. It means that with the passage of time, the DBF schemes are becoming fewer in LGO countries and they are moving towards DC schemes. It points out an important phenomenon where the countries are trying to shift their DB schemes towards DC schemes.

    Defined Contribution Fund (DC)

    Defined contribution funds (DCF) is portraying a relationship with the PFG in selected OECD countries at 1%, 10% and 5% levels of significance in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. It describes that if the DCF of a country is increased by one per cent, the PFG will also be increased by 0.271%, 0.224% and 0.308% in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. This relationship is also supported in the literature by (Benartzi, & Thaler, 2001; Holzmann, & Palmer, 2006; Choi et al. 2002; Cairns, Blake, & Dowd, 2006; Huberman, Iyengar, & Jiang, 2007). It also provides sustenance to the theory of pooling and prodigal father probability theory in the sense that every generating should save for its future. In sum, it provides strong support to the first developed hypothesis for this study i.e. H7 which mentions a strong positive association between DCF and PFG. By comparing HGO and LGO countries, we come to know that HGO countries have a lower coefficient (0.224) as linked to LGO countries (0.308). It indicates that in LGO countries the defined contribution schemes are growing faster as compared to HGO countries. 

    Employees’ Contributions (ESTC)

    Employees' contributions (ESTC) have a significant and positive relationship with the growth of pension funds in selected OECD countries at 5%, 5% and 10% levels of significance in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. It describes that if the ESTC of a country is increased by one per cent, the PFG will also be increased by 0.237%, 0.266% and 0.166% in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. This relationship is also supported in the literature by (Byrne, 2007; Toshiki, 2009; Zhang, 2011). It also provides sustenance to the theory of pooling because employees pool together to save for their future. In sum, it provides strong support to the 8th developed hypothesis for this study i.e. H8 which mentions a strong positive association between ESTC and PFG. By comparing HGO and LGO countries, the coefficients of ESTC (0.266) in HGO countries are larger as compared to (0.166) in LGO countries. It means that employees are contributing much more in HGO countries to fund their retirement plans as compared to LGO countries. 

    Employers’ Contributions (ERTC)

    Employers’ contributions is showing a significant and positive relationship with PFG in selected OECD countries at 1% and 5% levels of significance in whole-sample and HGO-Countries respectively. It is showing a significant negative relationship at a 5% level of significance in LGO-Countries. It describes that if the ERTC of a country is increased by one per cent, the PFG will be increased by 0.038% and 0.069% in whole-sample and HGO-Countries respectively. On the other hand, a 1% increase in ERTC will decrease the PFG by 0.013% in LGO-Countries. This relationship is also supported in the literature by (Chen, & Wu, 2014; Ghilarducci, & Sun, 2006; Pensions, (2005). It also provides sustenance to the theory of pooling and the Welfarist approach in the sense that it is the employer's duty to take care of his employees even after their retirement. That's why he contributes to the pooled funds to feed them in the future. In sum, it provides strong support to the 9th developed hypothesis for this study i.e. H9 which mentions a strong positive association between ERTC and PFG. It is interesting to know that LGO countries have a negative relationship with the growth of pension funds. The reason behind this phenomenon is that in LGO countries, employers are decreasing their contributions towards pooled funds and rather they are trying to put more burdens on the shoulder of employees.  

    Operating Expenses (OE)

    Operating and administrative expenses (OE) is depicting a negative and significant relationship with the PFG at 1%, 5% and 10% levels of significance in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. It describes that if the OE of a country is increased by one per cent, the PFG will be decreased by 0.238%, 0.112% and 0.306% in whole-sample, HGO-Countries and LGO-Countries respectively. It also provides sustenance to the theory of accounting profitability theory and absolute matching concept in the sense that expenses must be minimized to generate good profits to meet current and future liabilities. Moreover, the current expenses must be written off from the current revenues to make the correct accounting procedure. Nonetheless, the increasing amount of expenses will lead to a decrease in profits and the pension fund will not grow. In sum, it provides strong support to the 10th developed hypothesis for this study i.e. H10 which mentions a strong negative association between OE and PFG. By comparing HGO and LGO countries, the coefficient 0.306 of for LGO countries is much larger as compared to 0.112 for HGO countries. It means that the relationship between OE and PFG is much stronger in LGO countries as compared to HGO countries.

    Conclusion

    This study examines the importance of pension fund accumulation elements that affect the growth of pension funds. With the help of the fixed effect technique, we built a dynamic panel data regression model. With the increase of pension funds in HGO and LGO countries, results demonstrate that PFG (lag-1), PPF (lag-2), PICF, DCF, DCP, DCU, and ESTC are displaying good and significant results. There is some evidence to suggest that DB, DBT, and DBM are effective in high-income nations, but that they are less effective in low-income ones, with inconsistent outcomes. It shows that with the passage of time, LGO countries are trying to shift their pension system from the DB system to the DC system. Moreover, OE shows negative and significant behaviour with PFG.  

    The fixed effect is good on the basis of R-square, F-value, AIC and BIC. Moreover, the Hausman specification test also favours the application of a fixed-effect approach. The p-values for testing the heteroskedasticity and serial correlation do not show their presence in the data by accepting their null hypothesis of having no heteroskedasticity and no serial correlation in the data. The VIF column in the correlation matrix does not show the presence of a multicollinearity problem in the observed variables. As a result, ideas such as utility theories, the theory of pooling, Institutionists' approaches and theory of immunization, life-cycle theory and accounting profitability theory, human capital spillover theory and absolute matching concepts are all supported. All in all, we can conclude that the elements outlined above have a contributory impact on the expansion of pension funds.

    Research Implication or Contribution

    This research adds to the body of knowledge by dividing OECD nations into LGO & HGO categories based on the rate of growth of their pension funds. In the case of defined benefit plans, LGO countries behave differently from HGO countries. OE for LGO countries is larger than those for HGO countries, which indicates that LGOs face higher legal and administrative costs in the management of pension funds. Using DPD-hierarchical regression, we were able to add all of the accumulation components that were lacking from past studies. 

    Researchers at the OECD can make use of this study to discover trends in the rise of pensions in high- and low-income nations. OECD-pension-outlook can publish these statistics to highlight the contrasting behaviour of LGO nations in relation to DB funds, DC funds, employers' contributions, and OE in comparison to HGO countries. OECD pension outlook LGO countries are transitioning from a DB to a DC pension system, and pension fund officials can offer policy proposals to help those who have reached retirement age.

    Research Limitations and Recommendations

    The Gini coefficient can also be used to split OECD countries based on other indicators, such as the growth of pension funds, however, this study focused on the latter. Research into the move from DB to DC systems and its causes and outcomes can be explored further. 

References

  • Ahola, K., Gould, R., Virtanen, M., Honkonen, T., Aromaa, A., & Lönnqvist, J. (2009). Occupational burnout as a predictor of disability pension: a population-based cohort study. Occupational and Environmental Medicine, 66(5), 284–290.
  • Alonso, J., Bjelic, J., Herrera, C., hormazabal, Ordooez, I., Romero, C., Tuesta, D., & Ugarte, A. (2010). Projections of the Impact of Pension Funds on Investment in Infrastructure and Growth in Latin America. SSRN Electronic Journal.
  • Auerbach, A. J., & Lee, R. D. (2006). Notional Defined Contribution Pension Systems in a Stochastic Context: Design and Stability. National Bureau of Economic Research, 43–68.
  • Augusto, V., & Dimitri, I. (1992). The rationale and performance of personal pension plans in Chile. Policy Research Flnandal Policy and Systems. 1-38.
  • Bateman, H., & Mitchell, O. S. (2004). New evidence on pension plan design and administrative expenses: the Australian experience. Journal of Pension Economics & Finance, 3(1), 63–76.
  • Benartzi, S., & Thaler, R. H. (2001). Naive Diversification Strategies in Defined Contribution Saving Plans. American Economic Review, 91(1), 79–98.
  • Boulier, J.-F., Huang, S., & Taillard, G. (2001). Optimal management under stochastic interest rates: the case of a protected defined contribution pension fund. Insurance Mathematics & Economics, 28(2), 173–189.
  • Byrne, A. (2007). Employee Saving and Investment Decisions in Defined Contribution Pension Plans: Survey Evidence from the UK. Financial Services Review, 16(1), 19–40.
  • Cairns, A. J. G., Blake, D., & Dowd, K. (2006). Stochastic lifestyling: Optimal dynamic asset allocation for defined contributionpension plans. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control, 30(5), 843–877.
  • Chen, A., Hentschel, F., & Klein, J. K. (2015). A utility-and CPT-based comparison of life insurance contracts with guarantees. Journal of Banking & Finance, 61, 327-339.
  • Chen, B. R., & Wu, M. (2014). Industrial Agglomeration and Employer Compliance with Social Security Contribution: Evidence from China. Journal of Regional Science, 54(4), 586–605.
  • Cheng, C. (2015). Essays on Defined Benefit Pension Insurance and Participating Life Insurance.
  • Choi, J. J., Laibson, D., Madrian, B. C., & Metrick, A. (2002). Defined Contribution Pensions: Plan Rules, Participant Decisions, and the Path of Least Resistance. National Bureau of Economic Research, 16(1), 67–114.
  • çıkgöz, E., Uygurtürk, H., & Korkmaz, T. (2015). Analysis of factors affecting growth of pension mutual funds in Turkey. International Journal of Economics and Financial Issues, 5(2), 427- 433.
  • Clark, R. L., Glickstein, A., & Hill, T. (2013). Converting Traditional Defined Benefit Plans to Hybrid Plans: A Decade of Change. The Journal of Retirement, 1(2), 101–112.
  • Collins, S. (2003). The Expenses of Defined Benefit Pension Plans and Mutual Funds.
  • Engelhardt, G. V. (2011, October 1). The Pension Protection Act of 2006 and Diversification of Employer Stock in Defined Contribution Plans. Papers.ssrn.com.
  • Faccio, M., & Lasfer, M. A. (2000). Do Occupational Pension Funds Monitor Companies in Which They Hold Large Stakes. Journal of Corporate Finance, 6(1), 71–110.
  • Fronstin, P. (2001). Defined Contribution Health Benefits. EBRI Issue Brief / Employee Benefit Research Institute. 1-32.
  • Gerrard, R., Haberman, S., & Vigna, E. (2004). Optimal investment choices post- retirement in a defined contribution pension scheme. Insurance Mathematics & Economics, 35(2), 321–342.
  • Ghilarducci, T., & Sun, W. (2006). How defined contribution plans and 401(k)s affect employer pension costs. Journal of Pension Economics & Finance, 5(2), 175– 196.
  • Guo, Y., Tian, M., Han, K., Johnson, K., & Zhao, L. (2016). What determines pension insurance participation in China? Triangulation and the intertwined relationship among employers, employees and the government. The International Journal of Human Resource Management, 27(18), 2142-2160.
  • Ha, H. T. H. (2017). Legal aspects of pension product-review of the client's rights and tax incentives related to voluntary pension insurance business.
  • Haukenes, I., Mykletun, A., Knudsen, A. K., Hansen, H.-T., & Mæland, J. G. (2011). Disability pension by occupational class - the impact of work-related factors: The Hordaland Health Study Cohort. BMC Public Health, 11(1), 406–406.
  • Heeder, K. (2010). A Statistical Analysis of Defined Benefit, Defined Contribution, and Hybrid Plans.
  • Holzmann, R., & Palmer, E. E. (2006). Pension Reform: Issues and Prospects for Non- Financial Defined Contribution (NDC) Schemes. World Bank Publications.1–370.
  • Holzmann, R., Palmer, E. E., & Robalino, D. A. (2012). Nonfinancial defined contribution pension schemes in a changing pension world. 1–368.
  • Huberman, G., Iyengar, S. S., & Jiang, W. (2007). Defined Contribution Pension Plans: Determinants of Participation and Contributions Rates . Journal of Financial Services Research, 31(1), 1–32.
  • Jiang, X. (2011). The Smoothing of Pension Expenses: A Panel Analysis. Review of Quantitative Finance and Accounting, 37(4), 451–476.
  • Konstantin, M. (2007). Why Liberals Should Enthusiastically Support Social Security Personal Accounts. The Economists’ Voice, 4(6), 1–4.
  • Lamla, B., & Coppola, M. (2013). Is it All About Access? Perceived Access to Occupational Pensions in Germany.
  • Lucas, D., & Zeldes, S. P. (2007). Valuing and Hedging Defined Benefit Pension Obligations - The Role of Stocks Revisited. Money Macro and Finance (MMF) Research Group Conference 2006.
  • Mayhew, L., & Smith, D. (2014). Personal Care Savings Bonds: A New Way of Saving Towards Social Care in Later Life. Geneva Papers on Risk and Insurance-Issues and Practice, 39(4), 668–692.
  • Militaru, N. D. (2015). Analysis Of Correlation Between the Expenses Of Social Protection And The Anticipated Old Age Pension. Annals of University of Craiova - Economic Sciences Series, 1(43), 309– 314.
  • Njogu, E. W. (2014). Employee perception of the defined contribution pension scheme in the public sector.
  • Obinata, T. (2000). “Measurement of Periodical Pension Expenses”(in Japanese). CIRJE J-Series.
  • Olsen, K., & VanDerhei, J. (1997). Defined Contribution Plan Dominance Grows Across Sectors and Employer Sizes, While Mega Defined Benefit Plans Remain Strong: Where We are and Where We are Going. EBRI Issue Brief. 1-8.
  • Palme, M., & Svensson, I. (1997). Social Security, Occupational Pensions, and Retirement in Sweden. National Bureau of Economic Research, 355–402.
  • Pensions Commission. (2004). Pensions: Challenges and choices (Vol. 2). The Stationery Office.
  • Perozek, M. G., & Reinsdorf, M. B. (2002). Alternative Measures of Personal Saving.
  • Pesando, J. E. (2008). Risky Assumptions: A closer Look at the Bearing of Investment Risk in Defined-Benefit Pension Plans. C.D. Howe Institute Commentary, (266).
  • Poterba, J., Rauh, J., Venti, S., & Wise, D. (2006). Defined Contribution Plans, Defined Benefit Plans, and the Accumulation of Retirement Wealth.
  • Poterba, J. M., Venti, S. F., & Wise, D. A. (2001). The Transition to Personal Accounts and Increasing Retirement Wealth: Macro and Micro Evidence. National Bureau of Economic Research, 17–80.
  • Singh, T., & Mehta, S. (2015). Developing relationship between tax structure, pension funds and economic growth in oecd nations. JIMS8M: The Journal of Indian Management & Strategy, 20(3), 34– 41.
  • Stiff, G., Sharpe, M., & Atkinson, L. W. (2005). System and method for imbedding a defined benefit in a defined contribution plan.
  • Toshiki, N. (2009). System and method for warning employee portfolio deviation in corporate defined contribution pension.
  • Van Praag, B. M. S., & Hop, J. P. (2018). Demography and Provisions for Retirement: The Pension Composition, an Equilibrium Approach.
  • Zhang, W. (2011). The Tradeoff Between Employee Ownership and CEO Compensation: Evidence from Defined Contribution Pension Plans.
  • Zhu, X. M., Hardy, M. R., & Saunders, D. (2017). Valuation of an Early Exercise Defined Benefit (DB) Underpin Hybrid Pension Benefit. Social Science Research Network.
  • Zhu, X., Hardy, M., & Saunders, D. (2018). Valuation of an early exercise defined benefit underpins hybrid pension. Scandinavian Actuarial Journal, 2018(9), 823–844.

Cite this article

    APA : Qayyum, A., Arslan, A., & Ayyubi, S. (2022). Shifting Patterns from Defined Benefit to Defined Contributions: An Empirical Analysis of Selected OECD Countries. Global Economics Review, VII(I), 177-193 . https://doi.org/10.31703/ger.2022(VII-I).15
    CHICAGO : Qayyum, Arslan, Aniqa Arslan, and Shariq Ayyubi. 2022. "Shifting Patterns from Defined Benefit to Defined Contributions: An Empirical Analysis of Selected OECD Countries." Global Economics Review, VII (I): 177-193 doi: 10.31703/ger.2022(VII-I).15
    HARVARD : QAYYUM, A., ARSLAN, A. & AYYUBI, S. 2022. Shifting Patterns from Defined Benefit to Defined Contributions: An Empirical Analysis of Selected OECD Countries. Global Economics Review, VII, 177-193 .
    MHRA : Qayyum, Arslan, Aniqa Arslan, and Shariq Ayyubi. 2022. "Shifting Patterns from Defined Benefit to Defined Contributions: An Empirical Analysis of Selected OECD Countries." Global Economics Review, VII: 177-193
    MLA : Qayyum, Arslan, Aniqa Arslan, and Shariq Ayyubi. "Shifting Patterns from Defined Benefit to Defined Contributions: An Empirical Analysis of Selected OECD Countries." Global Economics Review, VII.I (2022): 177-193 Print.
    OXFORD : Qayyum, Arslan, Arslan, Aniqa, and Ayyubi, Shariq (2022), "Shifting Patterns from Defined Benefit to Defined Contributions: An Empirical Analysis of Selected OECD Countries", Global Economics Review, VII (I), 177-193
    TURABIAN : Qayyum, Arslan, Aniqa Arslan, and Shariq Ayyubi. "Shifting Patterns from Defined Benefit to Defined Contributions: An Empirical Analysis of Selected OECD Countries." Global Economics Review VII, no. I (2022): 177-193 . https://doi.org/10.31703/ger.2022(VII-I).15